Hindu Vivek Kendra
A RESOURCE CENTER FOR THE PROMOTION OF HINDUTVA
   
 
 
«« Back
Poverty and populism

Poverty and populism

Author: Balbir Punj
Publication: The Asian Age
Date: September 17, 2002

I hold Ms Shabana Azmi in high esteem, both as an actress and a Rajya Sabha colleague. The popular cine actress is also a goodwill ambassador for the United Nations Population Fund (UNPF).

Hence, it is expected of her to extend the UNPF line of advocating a reduction in birth rates as an instrument to attack poverty. So when Ms Azmi turns around and attacks the use of incentives and disincentives to curb population growth, under the plea that these measures are anti-poor and amount to the penalisation of the victims, one wonders whether the voice of the UNPF ambassador has been distorted by the traditional Leftist approach of keeping the poor in perpetual poverty.

The population of India which stood at 102.7 crore on March 1, 2001 is increasing by about 1.8 crore every year. India became the second country in the world after China to cross the 1 billion mark. India accounts for a mere 2.4 per cent of the world's surface area but it supports and sustains 16.7 per cent of the global population. By 2050 India will most likely overtake China to become the most populous country in the world.

As per the United Nations estimates, world population grew at an annual rate of 1.4 per cent during the decade of 1990-2000. China registered a much lower annual population growth rate of 1 per cent during the same period compared to about 1.9 per cent in the case of India. The population of India, which at the turn of the 20th century was only around 23.8 crore, increased by more than four times in the period of 100 years to reach 102.7 crore at the turn of the 21st century.

Interestingly, the population of India grew by one and a half times in the first half of the 20th century and in the second half it recorded a phenomenal three-fold increase. Therefore, India's need for an effective population policy can seldom be over-emphasised. The population scenario, in fact, is quite bleak in Asia and Africa. It fuels a sense of desperation - that it might be too late if population growth is not curbed now.

It is against this backdrop one has to weigh Ms Azmi's arguments. Surely she has a point against coercion and targeting people, as that can defeat the purpose of family planning. There is little wisdom in denying hospital facility to a woman who already has two children and is about to deliver her third. Ms Azmi may be right that in India, and in many other developing countries, it is not the woman but the man and at times even family heads who take the decision on childbirth. Unless the woman has the final say on this matter, disqualifying her from her job and taking other similar steps can amount to victimisation.

But at the same time we must answer certain questions. If disincentives mean penalising the victim, and repeated pregnancies are not good, then how do we rectify the situation? Ms Azmi advises medicare facilities, high literacy and economic independence for women. Sure enough, but will any government be able to provide enough hospitals, schools etc. to the people if population growth rate goes out of control, particularly in states like UP, Bihar and Orissa? Is not this a case of which came first, the chicken or the egg?

Then there is the question of female literacy and empowerment, which the Leftists claim to strongly support. But why are they selective about its implementation only on the majority community? If coercion is bad for planned population policies, why don't they start with compulsory female education? Or is that another form of coercion? In some communities women are subjected to divorce at will (of the men) and any attempt to change this status is met with an argument that it is a coercion of minorities. In fact divorce at will, polygamy and very low school enrolment rate for women, all seem to go hand in hand.

In the conspicuous absence of any effort to reform from within, should not small incentives and disincentives act as checks and balances? Should there not be a movement for 100 per cent enrolment of Muslim girls to modern schools, pushing them into employment to bolster economic independence?

She should push forward their case for greater female literacy, empowerment of women, and protection against arbitrary divorce. Why is it that in the southern states, say Kerala, where healthcare facilities are the best in the country, birth rate doesn't go down amongst certain communities? Or does the insistence on a two-child norm affect the long-term political agenda of these communities?

The higher rate of population growth among the Muslims of the Indian subcontinent has altered the demographic picture. A.P. Joshi, M.D. Srinivas and J.K. Bajaj of the Centre for Policy Studies, Chennai have recently finished working on a 350-page report titled Religious Demography of India.

Awaiting its official release, the study promises to be a classic collage of population data relevant to India in particular and the world in general. It observes: "The proportion of Indian religionists in the population of India (including Pakistan and Bangladesh) has declined by 11 percentage points of 110 years for which census information is available. Indian religionists formed 79.32 per cent of population in 1881 and 68.03 per cent in 1991. This is an extraordinary decline to take place in just about a century. If the trend of decline seen during 1881-1991 continues, then the proportion of Indian religionists in India (including Pakistan and Bangladesh) is likely to fall below 50 per cent early in the latter half of twenty-first century."

Within India proper, the decline suffered by Indian religionists is less pronounced - from 86.64 per cent in 1901 to 85.09 in 1991. But in some pockets, especially in the border areas, the Muslim population has seen an increase. In Kerala, the Hindus had lost six percentage points to Christians in the pre-Partition period, between 1901 and 1941. But in the post-Partition period between 1951 and 1991 they lost six per cent to the Muslims.

In the heartland and eastern regions of the Indian Union, comprising Uttar Pradesh, Bihar, West Bengal and Assam, Hindus have suffered a setback of four percentage points in the four decades between 1951 and 1991. In the northern border belt extending across Uttar Pradesh, Bihar, West Bengal and Assam, the post-Partition Muslim rate of growth has earned it seven percentage points in the demographic share. It will be naïve secularism to opine that the high population growth among Muslims in this sensitive belt is innocuous.

"More women die of pregnancy related issues in one week in India than all of Europe in a whole year," reminds Ms Azmi. True, and that is certainly bad. But at least this is confined to the Bimaru states and does not extend to the southern and the western states.

But worse things are happening in some neighbouring countries. Pakistan, has one of the highest infant and maternal mortality rates in the world. This is partly due to the pressure on the hapless uneducated women with hardly any independent means of livelihood to give birth. They fear that their men will desert them. There is a popular saying in Bangladesh, "Those who are fortunate, lose their wives, those who are less fortunate lose their cows." Few raise their voices again this inequality.

Ms Azmi is right when she says that if you deny ration to a poor family with three children because they have violated the two-child norm, it would worsen the situation. This is a paradox because it is the poor who need the maximum help and it is they who cannot practice population control for various reasons. But what happens when the poor are not motivated to practice it? They are caught in a vicious cycle of poverty. So is not a little coercion that might help them in the long run better than condemning them to perpetual poverty?

Studies have shown that economic improvement has inevitably followed the two-child norm and responsible parenthood. It has never been the other way round. Communities, which were compelled by law to abandon their traditional practice of having more than one wife, discontinued child marriage and sent their girls to school. Hence, a limited package of incentives or disincentives will have a far better result.

Recently the Central government enacted a marriage, inheritance and divorce reform law for Christians with help from the Supreme Court, pressure from the community's own leaders and enlightened public opinion, in spite of opposition from some conservatives. A courageous woman, Mary Roy, fought till the Supreme Court reformed the Christian Inheritance Law. But what happened when the Supreme Court and enlightened public opinion sought to reform the Marriage and Divorce Law among Muslims in the Eighties? The contrast between the impacts that Mary Roy and Shah Bano had on their respective communities is worth a study in how reforms are implemented or blocked.

In my opinion, goodwill doesn't mean refusal to initiate, legislate or campaign for social reforms. Why do Leftists often seem to support the fundamentalist; and reformist beacons like Ms Azmi at times seem to argue on the same side as Shahi Imam and Syed Shahabuddin? Should not Shabana resurrect Shah Bano?

(Balbir K. Punj is a Rajya Sabha MP and convenor of the BJP Think Tank and can be contacted at bpunj@email.com)
 


Back                          Top

«« Back
 
 
 
  Search Articles
 
  Special Annoucements